The Overfishing Problem, by Don Orth
When did our overfishing problems begin? Hugo Grotius, a Dutch philosopher and jurist, proposed that in times of peace, high seas are open to all nations and may not be subjected to national sovereignty. This “freedom of the seas” doctrine, first proposed as early as 1609, was eventually accepted among international freedoms, particularly laissez-faire economics in the 19thcentury. The doctrine was vigorously supported by dominant powers at the time, especially Great Britain. In the late 19thcentury, fishermen and some fisheries biologists argued strongly against all restrictive measures on the basis of the inexhaustible nature of the fishery resources of the sea. In 1883, Thomas Henry Huxley extended the thinking of the freedom of the seas to fisheries. “I believe then, that the cod fishery, the herring fishery, the pilchard fishery, the mackerel fishery, and probably all the great sea fisheries, are inexhaustible… and any attempt to regulate these fisheries seems consequently, from the nature of the case, to be useless.” Thomas Henry Huxley 1883. If the overfishing problem did not exist, there would be no need for fisheries science to develop. However, steam-powered trawling in the 1880's and improvements in trawling technology in the early 20thcentury had an enormous, unappreciated effect on the fishing capacity. Many fish stocks were in decline, and more boats and more fisherman were fishing harder for fewer and fewer fish. North Sea government commissions began to collect fisheries data to deal with the overfishing problem by providing better numbers. Petersen (1900-1903) first developed an approach to estimate overfishing, which eventually led to important developments in fisheries science. The first empirical evidence to support the overfishing problem was collected during World War I, during which fishing was sharply curtailed in European waters and exploited fish populations increased dramatically. Fish marking experiments initiated by Danish biologist C. G. J. Petersen and others further showed that fishing was a major cause of fish mortality in developed fisheries. At the same time, Heincke (1913) developed the first catch-curve approach to estimate mortality. Huntsman (1944) defined the overfishing problem as the point “Where the take in proportion to the effort fails to yield a satisfactory living to the fisherman.” Eventually, fisheries scientists proposed a Great Law of Fishing -- “Fisheries that are unlimited become unprofitable.” Graham (1943). Russian professor, Fedor Baranov, the “Grandfather of fisheries population dynamics”, Quinn (2003), first explained the problem in economic terms. “As we see, a picture is obtained which diverges radically from the hypothesis which has been favoured almost down to the present time, namely that the natural reserve of fish is an inviolable capital, of which the fishing industry must use only the interest, not touching the capital at all. Our theory says, on the contrary, that a fishery and a natural reserve of fish are incompatible, and that the exploitable stock of fish is a changeable quantity, which depends on the intensity of the fishery. The more fish we take from a body of water, the smaller is the basic stock remaining in it; and the less fish we take, the greater is the basic stock, approximating to the natural stock when the fishery approaches zero. Such is the nature of the matter.” Baranov, F. (1918, translated by W.E. Ricker 1945, mimeograph, cited in Gordon 1954). Baranov’s seminal contribution was the solution to the catch equation. Baranov's catch equation, where C is catch, F is fishing mortality, M is natural mortality, T is time, N0 is cohort number at time zero, and e is Euler's constant. Where C is annual catch, N is abundance, F is fishing mortality, and M is natural mortality. Quinn (2003), in a review of fisheries models, writes that Baranov’s catch equation is “probably the most used in all of fisheries modeling.” Russell (1931, 1942) developed a simple algebraic equation S2= S1+ (A + G) – (C + M) to account for changes in total weight of the catchable stock of a particular size. Here S1is the weight of the catchable stock at the beginning of year, S2 is weight of the catchable stock at end of the year, and A represents additions to the catchable stock, G is growth of individuals that survive, C is catch, and M is non-fishing mortality. Russell’s theoretical contributions could now be incorporated in practical determinations of overfishing. During the period after World War I and the acceptance of overfishing, many scientists made important development of fisheries models for fish population dynamics. Read Quinn’s (2003) review -- it will answer students' questions about where all these population dynamics equations came from. Getting better numbers for these models remains a high priority for solving the overfishing problem. Unfortunately, what happened when we defined the overfi
Baranov's catch equation, where C is catch, F is fishing mortality, M is natural mortality, T is time, N0 is cohort number at time zero, and e is Euler's constant. |
Trends in world capture fisheries and aquaculture. Source: FAO. |
Fishers display a day's catch in Manteo, North Carolina, before limits were imposed in 1979. Striped bass were in decline in virtually every drainage area from Maine to Florida. CC-BY-2.0 Source. |
What's Your Reaction?